Ideas

Get new ideas, stories and articles on progressive capitalism in a short, weekly email. Enter your email here.


    This is stored in Mailchimp and will only be used to send you this newsletter.

    Category:

    Value Vacuums

    January 7, 2022 in Land, Value

    In some markets there exists organisations that act as a black hole for value and profits. They are a gravity well, sucking all of the excess fat from companies above and below in the supply chain and growing their bottom line as they do it.

    When I worked in telecoms, a colleague once remarked that the hardest place to make a profit in the industry is the retail division of the monopoly wholesaler. This struck me as quite counter-intuitive until he explained how value vacuums work.

    How Value Vacuums Work

    In many European markets, it’s very common to find a story like this…. “LaTelco” is a former state monopoly that manages all of the phone and broadband lines and infrastructure in the country. An average household can become a customer of LaTelco for home phone and broadband. To encourage competition in the market, regulations forced LaTelco to open up their infrastructure and allow other companies to re-sell broadband and phone services to local households.

    This is a common regulatory move in broadband, mobile and energy markets across the world, intended to increase competition and lower prices.

    LaTelco now has two units – LaTelco Wholesale, which manages the broadband lines and physical infrastructure and LaTelco Retail, which manages customer service and billing and sales. LaTelco Retail competes with other similar retailers, all of whom are selling the same underlying service provided by LaTelco Wholesale.

    Under regulation, the wholesaler has to supply services at the same rate to all retail companies. My colleague explained that the LaTelco had two choices to maximise their profits. In the first, the wholesale unit could set the price quite low. The retail unit could buy electricity cheap and sell it at a reasonable rate, then make a decent profit. This also is true of it’s retail competitors.

    Alternatively, the wholesaler could set a high price, making a high profit for itself. It would squeeze all the profit out of it’s own retail arm, which isn’t ideal, but it would also squeeze the profit out of the retail competitors.

    It’s not hard to see what the optimal strategy is here, and which the parent company would often chose. In the second option they can use their pricing power to capture the excess value in the entire market, rather than just the market share of it’s retail unit in the first option.

    All of the profit in the top layer is sucked down to the wholesaler

    This is why my friend’s job, as a manager tasked with making the retail unit profitable, was a tough one!

    In cases like these, wholesale supplier can act as a Value Vaccum, hoovering up all the profits from the companies they supply.

    From a societal perspective, this is very far from ideal. Why should the retailers continue to innovate, cut costs or improve service, when every bit of margin they generate will ultimately accrue to the layer below them?

    Why McDonalds is a Real Estate Company

    Ray Kroc, the first CEO of McDonalds, famously hit on this realisation in 1956 when he changed the business model of the McDonalds franchise system. Instead of trying to make his fortune from a small percentage of each burger sale, he instead started buying the land on which each McDonald’s franchise was built and locking the franchise owner into a long-term lease.

    By owning the land, Kroc was able to use rent prices to capture the lions share of value created by each restaurant.

    Tren Griffin, who calls this effect “Wholesale Transfer Pricing,” shared a story of the Wild Ginger restaurant in Seattle

    The restaurant was a huge success. When lease renewal time came up for Wild Ginger the landlord wanted a massive rent increase. The ability of the landlord to demand that increase is wholesale pricing power.

    In this situation, people often have the option to move premises (at great cost), but in times of limited supply, like now, Land can act as the ultimate vacuum because, as Mark Twain noted, they’re not making it any more.

    In times like these, the technique Ray Kroc used to capture the majority of value created by restaurant owners is now happing at a society wide level.

    Land owners are capturing huge amounts of the value that productivity growth is creating in society.

    Look at San Francisco, for example. Young workers are getting huge salaries from tech companies, but paying huge amounts of that out in rent. Huge amounts of the value created by the tech revolution should be accruing to workers, but is instead hoovered up in Value Vacuums by land owners, who played very little part in the creation of that value.

    There are, of course, ways to weaken the power of Value Vacuums. Introducing competitors, regulations and price controls, and even wider shifts like the introduction of remote working, or the provision of public transport, can alter the dynamics.

    Value Vacuums are something we should always be mindful of, to combat their ability to distort markets and separate value creation from value capture.

    Competition is Like Magic

    December 11, 2020 in Competition

    In the late 1800s, two German philosophers described the awesome (in the original sense of the word) power of “free competition” as they called it.

    They remarked that, what we might call market-based economies today, had unleashed in humans a productive capacity not only unseen before, but completely surpassing imagination.

    In 1848 they remarked that free competition “has created more massive and more colossal productive forces than have all preceding generations together. [….] — what earlier century had even a presentiment that such productive forces slumbered in the lap of social labour?”

    These German philosophers were, of course, Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels. The quote above is from The Communist Manifesto.

    They understood clearly, as we do now, that using competitive markets as a way to organise the work that people do is the most powerful enabler of productive capacity we have yet discovered.

    Their concern was that this process was so powerful and so unwieldy that we had unleashed a force we couldn’t control, “like the sorcerer who is no longer able to control the powers of the nether world whom he has called up by his spells.”

    A Process With No Goal

    Two years later, another philosopher proposed an extraordinary explanation for the diversity of life. Unlike almost all attempts at explanation before, this one did not talk about goals that organisms and species were trying to achieve, only the process by which they came about.

    Millenia prior to this, Aristotle had declared that a full explanation of anything must consider its final cause, what goal it was trying to achieve, but in 1850 Darwin introduced us to the idea of evolution as a theory of life that didn’t include a goal that it was working towards.

    A fundamental theory of life that only talks about process, without talking about goals. Wild stuff! Aristotle’s head would have been spinning.

    Competition as an organising principle can be described in the same way. An incredibly powerful process, but one without a goal. Indeed, that’s what makes it so powerful, that the process is more important that the end-point.

    This is true of the scientific method too, a powerful process for discovering the unknown outcome.

    Much More Things

    You can’t say that evolution is “good” or “bad”, it’s just a process. It produced all that we find wondrous in nature, and all that is “red in tooth and claw”.

    The scientific process produced discoveries that led to the atomic bomb and the polio vaccine.

    So too competitive markets allow us to do much more of things, whether they’re the right things or not.

    It’s Just a Tool

    By definition then, this process can’t be your ideology. It can’t be a philosophy you live by, a statement of how the world should be which you defend at all costs. It can only be a tool you use, when applicable, to get there. It is your vehicle, not your goal.

    To describe yourself as a “free-market guy” is as meaningless as describing yourself as an “experimenter”. That’s cool, but for what?

    We have wrangled the scientific process as a tool and we direct it towards our goals. We don’t know the outcomes of the experiments, but we certainly choose which experiments to run. We might not know the answer in advance, but we can aim within a range of possibilities.

    Competitive markets are the greatest organisational tool we have for productivity, but their power is precisely what gives them destructive capability.

    Set “free” as they have been since the 1980s leaves us in a position like the sorcerer’s apprentice, unable to direct them towards outcomes that benefit us all.

    Let’s recognise them as powerful tools, not to be approached with hubris, but also not to be lauded for their own sake.

    Living in A Competitive Economy is Exhausting

    December 9, 2020 in Competition

    For those of us who defend the positives of capitalism, the first place we usually start is competition.

    There are many more parts to capitalism than just competition, but the most popular conception of capitalism is as a system that uses competition as an organising principle.

    People do things for friends out of friendship, for family out of love and for their close community based on shared narratives and a promise of reciprocity.

    Beyond this, when we want to co-operate at scale, when we want to trade time and energy with strangers, one of the best methods or organising that are by creating competitive markets.

    Competition as a very valuable organising principle and I believe it’s one worth defending, but to do so blindly is naive. We should interrogate and acknowledge the many downsides of market economies, so that we can improve their weaknesses and better defend their virtues.

    When Workers Compete

    The benefits of a competitive labour market are easy to articulate. If everyone wants to invest time and effort in their education and training to get the best paying jobs, then the education levels, skills and productive capacity of the whole country rise.

    We all work hard, make good contributions and create value in part because it will put us in line for better jobs, higher salaries or career progression.

    An absence of any competitive tension could make us lazy, unproductive and unfulfilled.

    The theory makes sense, but there’s something very obviously missing from the last few sentences. We can feel it intuitively. Surely all our life can’t be about competing, comparing ourselves to our neighbours and investing in ways to eek out an edge?

    That sounds exhausting, both physically and emotionally.

    It sounds quite unfulfilling too. Surely we do better work when we co-operate instead of compete? Or at least a mixture of both?

    As for the theory that a complete absence of competition will cause laziness, a leaf through the history books will show us that a huge number of advances in our quality of life have come from artificially lowering competition, not increasing it.

    Creating and increasing the minimum wage, creating the five day and forty hour workweeks and introducing mandatory annual leave and bank holidays are all victories of the Union movement which could be described as reducing competition between workers, but all of which enhanced our quality of life.

    Competition is Good For Companies?

    If we benefit from artificially reducing competition between people when they work, surely competition between companies is unambiguously good?

    It’s true that we all benefit when companies are competing to provide products and services for us, but have you worked in highly competitive, low-margin businesses? It can be miserable.

    One of a dozen local coffee shops on the brink of bankruptcy. A discount airline with a 3% profit margin. A ruthlessly competitive supermarket. Not the kind of work environments we dream of when we think of dream jobs, full of stability and promise.

    Without a shadow of a doubt, the best times of my working career is when I’ve been working in high-margin, less competitive companies. Not un-competitive. I’m not making the case for monopolies, and I’m not suggesting that intense bursts of competition can’t help drive us to do some of our best work, but it’s undeniable that ferocious competitive environments can be gruelling and grinding.

    Competition is a Tool, Not A Lifestyle

    The inherent conflict here seems to be that we’re all the benefactors when strangers are competing for our money, but we’re the losers if we spend our lives constantly competing.

    Any economic philosophy with that claims blindly that “competition is good,” without nuance, talks to us only as recipients of the system, not as participants.

    It is unsurprising that among young people, anti-competitive ideas are gaining strong traction. If I lived in a constantly competitive system, from school to college to work, I’d push back against it too.

    Any progressive economic philosophy what wants to include the value of competitive markets (which it should), must recognise them as useful tools, but not an ideology.

    If competition can create great benefits, we need to balance it with time and space to enjoy the rewards. We can spend much of our time doing good work, but also make time to enjoy fruits of our labour.